Random articles

1. The left is beginning to understand that NIMBYs are the biggest enemy of the working class:

When there is not enough housing supply to go around, richer people will bid up the price of the housing units that exist, and poorer people will be forced to crowd into the shittier, less desirable housing units at the bottom. The only winners in this situation are the landlords (and existing homeowners) who own the existing housing supply, who are free to continue raising their prices, because the housing shortage means that people don’t have other choices. That includes major investment firms like Blackstone, who are happy to explain to their investors that the shortage of housing supply is what makes housing such a good investment. Right there in the Blackstone pitch deck, it says: “Chronic housing shortage exacerbated by recent supply declines support the pricing power of BREIT’s existing rental housing assets.” Everyone who inveighs against new housing construction because it might help out greedy developers is, in fact, playing into the hands of landlords and investment funds, who are happy to see the population suffer under a housing shortage because that shortage protects their pricing power. Congrats.

2. I frequently complain about the way America increasingly bullies the rest of the world (both enemies and allies.). Thus I was glad to see Tyler Cowen link to a new book by Henry Farrell and Abraham Newman entitled Underground Empire: How America Weaponized the World Economy. Amazon describes it as follows:

A deeply researched investigation that reveals how the United States is like a spider at the heart of an international web of surveillance and control, which it weaves in the form of globe-spanning networks such as fiber optic cables and obscure payment systems

America’s security state first started to weaponize these channels after 9/11, when they seemed like necessities to combat terrorism—but now they’re a matter of course. Multinational companies like AT&T and Citicorp build hubs, which they use to make money, but which the government can also deploy as choke points. Today’s headlines about trade wars, sanctions, and technology disputes are merely tremors hinting at far greater seismic shifts beneath the surface.

Slowly but surely, Washington has turned the most vital pathways of the world economy into tools of domination over foreign businesses and countries, whether they are rivals or allies, allowing the U.S. to maintain global supremacy. In the process, we have sleepwalked into a new struggle for empire. Using true stories, field-defining findings, and original reporting, Henry Farrell and Abraham Newman show how the most ordinary aspects of the post–Cold War economy have become realms of subterfuge and coercion, and what we must do to ensure that this new arms race doesn’t spiral out of control.

3. The Financial Times has an article explaining how smaller cities are outpacing large cities in the post-Covid period. They focus on my hometown. When I visited Madison during June of this year, I saw a flurry of new apartment construction.

4. This is the issue on which lab leakers should focus.

5. A study by Dhaval M. Dave, Yang Lian, Caterina Muratori, & Joseph J. Sabia found no evidence that pot legalization negatively impacts labor force participation:

Our study is the first to comprehensively explore the impact of recreational marijuana legalization on labor market outcomes of working‐​age individuals (aged 16–64). First, using data from the 2002–2020 National Survey on Drug Use and Health, we documented that RML adoption is associated with a 2–4 percentage point increase in adult marijuana use. We also found that the largest increase in marijuana consumption occurs a year after RML adoption.

Next, using monthly data from the Current Population Survey outgoing rotation groups, we found little evidence that RML adoption has an impact on the probability of employment or on wages of all working‐​age individuals. We also examined the effects of RMLs where recreational sales were allowed (i.e., at dispensaries) and for various working‐​age populations by age, gender, race/​ethnicity, and education and found little evidence of adverse labor market effects.

6. How do people become drug addicts? Here’s a typical case:

Joseph was a bright kid and four-season athlete who dreamed of a professional sports career.

He was studying physics and playing soccer at the University of South Florida when he sustained an injury on the field and was given opioid painkillers. Once his prescription ran out, he began buying pain pills on the street. That turned into buying heroin.

He came to Los Angeles for a rehab program about a decade ago and was in and out of treatment for most of his early 20s. Now at 32, he has been homeless for six years and has been addicted to fentanyl for the last four, he says.

Update: To be clear, I’m not blaming the addiction to fentanyl on Oxycontin, I’m blaming it on a lack of Oxycontin.

7. It looks like AI could already be leading to double digit GDP growth . . . 

. . . in Anguilla:

A tiny island in the Caribbean is now sitting on a digital treasure.

Anguilla, a tropical British territory, is known for its coral reefs and white sand beaches. Since the 1990s, however, it’s also been in charge of assigning internet addresses that end in .ai to residents and businesses looking to register websites. . . .

The total number of registrations of sites ending with these two letters has effectively doubled in the past year to 287,432, according to Vince Cate, who for decades has managed the .ai domain for Anguilla. Cate estimates Anguilla will bring in as much as $30 million in domain-registration fees for 2023. 

That’s roughly 10% of Anguilla’s GDP.

This is your economy on fentanyl

Another day, another upward revision over at the Atlanta Fed’s GDPNow:

Matt Yglesias is correct, this is good for the US economy in much the same way that fentanyl is good for one’s well-being. I’ve never taken that particular drug, but I imagine that it makes one feel good—for a while.

[Yeah, I know, Yglesias meant something else. 😉 ]

So what’s wrong with 5.8% RGDP growth? Nothing, as long as NGDP growth is below 5%. But let’s be real; if RGDP comes in at 5.8%, then NGDP growth (which is what matters) will be 8% or 9%. And that would increase the risk of recession in 2024.

On the other hand, Bloomberg says there’s a 100% chance of recession by October, so perhaps the Atlanta Fed is wrong.

When RGDP came in negative during the first two quarters of 2022, I recall Keynesians suggesting it was the lagged effect of the Fed signaling tighter money in late 2021. Hawkish forward guidance. So this growth (if it happens) would be the lagged effect of exactly what?

M2 leveled off after December 2021 and began falling after July 2022. Real M2 fell even earlier. So I’m not letting monetarists off the hook.

Even the markets have fallen a bit short.

As I keep saying, there’s not much evidence that the Fed adopted a contractionary policy in 2022.

All good arguments for level targeting.

PS. The case for optimism. And this.

The next 12 weeks

I believe that the next 12 weeks will be critical for the Fed’s anti-inflation program. During that period, we’ll get three more jobs reports and the 3rd quarter NGDP report. Hopefully, we’ll see a bit further progress on wage inflation, which is the only sort of inflation that actually matters for macroeconomic stability. And I hope that NGDP growth continues its recent downward trend (to 4.7% in Q2).

But that’s not what I expect to happen. I expect that NGDP will accelerate in Q3, perhaps to 7% or 8%. That would be bad! And I expect 12-month nominal wage growth (average hourly earnings) to accelerate above the current 4.4% figure. I hope I’m wrong, but I fear that the Fed still hasn’t actually achieved a contractionary monetary policy stance.

When will the tight money end? Perhaps the real question is, “When will the tight money begin?”

Come back in November, and you guys can all laugh at me if I’m wrong. Maybe we’ll be in recession. Heck, Bloomberg says there’s a 100% chance of recession by then.

PS. I see the media talking about how CPI inflation has fallen from 9% to 3.2%. I hope my readers are smart enough to ignore those sorts of meaningless data points.

PPS. Here’s the Atlanta Fed’s current forecast for Q3 real GDP. Currently, they predict 5% RGDP growth. To get nominal GDP growth (which is what the Fed should care about), you need to add inflation.

I’m with McAnally

This tweet shows a pretty obvious blind spot among people on the left:

So McAnally welcomes a major investment in his town, perhaps assuming that this represents the free market at work. Then he changes his mind when he finds out that it is an inefficient subsidized investment that results from a highly statist industrial policy regime. And for that he’s basically called a phony.

I’m with McAnally—buy the cheaper solar panels from China and produce goods and services here for which America has a comparative advantage. After all, it’s not like America is unable to create jobs for people that want to work.

PS. I know, “But if there’s war over Taiwan there might be a slight delay in the rate we can add solar panels to our rooftops!!!”

PPS. Over the past 12 years, I must have read 1000 commenters explaining to me their stupid theories about how politics work. Not one of those theories is able to explain this simple graph:

Biden’s secret agenda is to transfer billions of dollars from high taxpaying blue states to government dependent red states. ¯\_(ツ)_/¯

Why does demand affect prices?

Unfortunately, macroeconomists lack a common framework for thinking about how the macroeconomy works. David Beckworth directed me to a tweet that nicely illustrates this problem:

First, let me agree with Blanchard on one point. I would certainly expect a decline in inflation to be associated with a rise in unemployment. But his claim about the causal mechanism seems so strange to me that I even have trouble thinking of a way to explain why we disagree. If a student asked me “why does Blanchard think higher unemployment would reduce inflation?” I’d have trouble answering the question. That doesn’t mean he’s wrong, (he’s a far more distinguished economist than I am), it’s just that our approaches are so different.

Instead of starting with a sort of extreme Chicago/monetarist argument, let me start with an idea that once had strong support among Keynesian economists—incomes policies. Back in the 1970s, left-of-center economists in places like the US and Europe favored “incomes policies” (basically wage/price controls, with an emphasis on wages) as a way of reducing inflation. They didn’t believe this policy would do the job all by itself, rather they argued that it would allow other policies that slowed the growth in aggregate demand to reduce inflation with less of a side effect of high unemployment. So why did they believe this?

At the time, I assumed that incomes policy proponents bought into the “sticky wage/price” theory of macroeconomics. This is the idea that demand shocks have real effects because wages and prices are sticky in the short run. (Some argue that in the long run money is neutral and output returns to a natural rate. But that claim has no bearing on this post.)

So Keynesians seemed to believe that demand-side policies that reduced the growth rate of nominal spending would involve more output and less inflation if wages and prices could somehow be made more downward flexible. Incomes policies (if effective) were supposed to do this:

Lower NGDP —> Lower inflation & stable output

Here I have no interest in the question of whether incomes policies were effective; rather I’m focused on the mechanism by which they were supposed to work. It seems to me that that mechanism is completely at odds with Blanchard’s view of the problem.

I agree with Ricardo Reis, we should think of unemployment as an unfortunate side effect of policies that restrain demand to control inflation:

1. Contractionary demand side policies –> falling nominal spending

2. Sticky wages and prices

3. Reduced inflation as well as lower employment/output

Aggregate nominal spending is P*Y. If nominal spending falls by 10% and prices only fall by 4% (due to sticky wages and prices), then output and employment will necessarily decline. But that employment decline doesn’t seem causal.

When people talk of a causal role for unemployment I see:

1. Lower employment

2. ???

3. Lower inflation

To some people, that causal relationship might seem obvious. But to me it seems much more natural to see unemployment as a side effect. If wages and prices were completely flexible, it’s hard to see how changes in nominal spending would have any real effect on employment or output. In that case, what would be the causal mechanism between nominal spending and inflation?

You might argue, “But wages and prices are not completely flexible in the real world.” Yes, but that’s not the point when trying to understand the causal mechanism. If it were really true that unemployment is the causal mechanism, then in a world where wages and prices were 100% flexible and the economy always stayed at the natural rate there’d be no way to slow inflation with contractionary monetary policies. Does anyone believe that?

Recall that a lower price level is equivalent to a higher value (purchasing power) of money, the unit of account. Blanchard is basically saying that the only (demand-side) mechanism by which we can give money more value is by creating unemployment. Now consider a microeconomic analogy to his claim:

Assume a shock to the apple market that raises the equilibrium price of apples, such as a change in consumer preferences or a crop failure. That rise in apple prices might be associated with a situation where grocery stores were temporarily out of apples. Maybe they didn’t immediately raise the posted price, and consumers exhausted the existing stock.

Even if there were a temporary apple shortage, I think it would be weird to view the shortage as causing the higher apple prices—it was the reduction in supply an/or the increase in demand that caused the higher apple prices. There might be a temporary shortage if apple prices were sticky. But I can also imagine a scenario where apple prices were flexible, and there were no shortages during the transition to higher prices. In that case, in what sense would shortages be the causal factor for higher prices? You can reverse this example for surpluses of apples when the price declines.

When overall inflation declines, it’s the reduction in AD and/or the rise in AS that causes the decline. Unemployment might rise as a side effect, but it’s hard to see how it’s the causal factor. It’s an unfortunate side effect of sticky wages and prices leading to disequilibrium. But disequilibrium doesn’t cause the lower inflation; indeed inflation would actually fall faster if the real economy stayed at equilibrium when nominal spending slowed. In that case, a sudden 10% fall in NGDP would immediately reduce prices by the full 10%.

Here’s another example. Apartment rents often decline when there are a lot of vacancies. But building a lot of new apartment buildings should reduce rents even if the vacancy level never rises. Vacancies aren’t a causal factor; they are evidence of a market out of equilibrium. It’s the supply and demand for housing that drive the process.

Even if the correlation between lower inflation and higher unemployment were 100%, if wages and prices were always sticky, it still doesn’t make unemployment causal. If you told me that 100% of people with Covid had a fever, I still wouldn’t believe that fevers cause Covid.

Update: Ricardo Reis has an excellent thread on this issue.

PS. I have a related post at Econlog.

PPS. As an aside, the 1971-74 incomes policy failed in the US because policymakers failed to enact contractionary fiscal and monetary policies during the control period. So the proposed policy was never actually tried. NGDP growth remained very high and (not surprisingly) inflation rose after the controls were lifted. I’m not a fan of incomes policies, just pointing out that this outcome has no bearing on the issues in this post. I mentioned incomes policies only to better understand the thought process of its Keynesian proponents.