Real interest rates are not much better
It’s widely known that nominal interest rates are not a good indicator of the stance of monetary policy. Actually it’s probably not widely known, which is a major puzzle in and of itself.
Yes, there is a liquidity effect. A sudden increase in the money supply will often reduce short term interest rates. But other factors have a much more powerful impact on rates, and hence the liquidity effect can be very elusive and hard to spot.
Some economists think this can be fixed by looking at real interest rates. But that’s false. Soon after I criticized a recent post by John Quiggin, he added a couple more paragraphs, and shifted his argument from nominal rates to real rates:
Update As pointed out by Mark Sadowski in comments, these are nominal rates of interest. To get the real rate, which is more relevant, you need to subtract the expected rate of inflation, which fell from around 7 per cent to around 4 per cent over this period (as measured by surveys, and by the premium for inflation-adjusted Treasury bonds). So, you get a 9 percentage point reduction in the real rate from 10 per cent to 1 per cent. This doesn’t make much difference to the story. Most economists would regard policy as contractionary/expansionary if real interest rates are above/below the long-run neutral level, about 3 per cent. So, we still have a shift from strongly contractionary to moderately expansionary.
That’s sort of like saying “most economists” are ignorant of the basic principles of monetary economics. But maybe they are. It is a highly specialized field.
Think about why some economists might prefer using real interest rates to nominal rates. What is the reason? Obviously the reason is that economists understand that interest rates don’t just reflect the liquidity effect, expected inflation also influences interest rates. Fair enough. But why stop there? Expected income growth as well as the level of income also have powerful effects on interest rates. Indeed if you go back to the pre-WWI period in America we had almost no expected inflation, and no Federal Reserve to raise or lower interest rates. And guess what; rates rose and fell with the business cycle, just as they do today. Income has an incredibly powerful impact on rates, indeed in recent years much more so that inflation. That’s why Ben Bernanke insists that neither nominal nor real interest rates are reliable indicators of monetary policy, and you must look at NGDP growth and inflation. But then Bernanke is not “most economists” he’s one of the leading experts in monetary economics.
Quiggin continues:
However, market monetarists want to argue that the stance of policy should be assessed relative to a policy rule (Taylor rule or NGDP) that already incorporates a prescription of cutting rates when GDP falls and unemployment rises. This doesn’t make a lot of sense to me. It’s like arguing that Obama’s stimulus was actually a contractionary policy because it wasn’t as big as (according to a standard analysis based on Okun’s Law) it should have been. It’s partly a question of semantics, but it’s associated with the claim that, if only rates had been cut even more, we wouldn’t have had the recession, or would have recovered quickly. Having been around at the time, I disagree.
No, that’s not the claim. If rates had been cut to zero I’d guess the recession would have been far deeper. Zero rate cuts are almost always associated with ultra-deep recessions. With tight money. The US in the 1930s. Japan since 1997. One more time:
NEVER REASON FROM A PRICE CHANGE
What would have prevented a deep recession would have been a more expansionary monetary policy, not lower rates. Interest rates tell us almost nothing about whether monetary policy is expansionary or not. If anything, they tend to be a “reverse indicator.” If you told me that country X had 40% interest rates, I’d guess they had a highly expansionary monetary policy.
Quiggin seems to think that MMs are sort of oddballs. OK, but what does he make of the Volcker disinflation?
1980:3 to 1981:3: NGDP growth = 14.0%
1981:3 to 1982:3: NGDP growth = 3.2%
Meanwhile nominal interest rates on 3 month T-bills fell from 16.3% in May 1981 to 7.71% in October 1982. These data are quite similar to the Australian episode considered by Quiggin. If we use his criterion for easy money then America’s most famous tight money policy since the Great Depression was actually an expansionary monetary policy.
I don’t think so.
PS. Real interest rates on 5 year Treasury debt (ex ante, risk free) rose from a low of 0.57% in July 2008 to a peak of 4.2% at the beginning of December 2008. Throughout this period the US was NOT at the zero bound. Maybe you guys can help me. Find examples from Quiggin or any other Keynesian blogger in late 2008 complaining about the Fed’s ultra-tight money policy.
Can’t find any examples? Keep trying; they must be out there somewhere. After all the smarter Keynesians like Quiggin insist that while nominal rates are not reliable, surely real interest rates are. So find me some examples. To paraphrase Bob Dole; “where was the outrage?”
PPS. Quiggin’s fiscal policy analogy makes no sense, as the change in the money supply would be the closest analogy to deficit spending. Both interest rates and NGDP are market variables that are affected by changes in the money supply. Of course there are other differences. Fiscal stimulus is costly whereas monetary stimulus is not. Hence monetary policy is best viewed as setting the steering on a ship, where no one direction is more costly than another, just different. And NGDP is the best way of measuring direction; interest rates are almost meaningless.