Related posts
I didn’t have time to blog today, so here are some interesting posts that relate to issues I’ve been discussing.
James Hamilton on the implications of the oil spill:
I agree with Ed [Dolan] that intra-organizational incentives contributed to the problem in both cases, and that government policy allowed the firms that created the problems to pass some of the costs on to others in many details of the financial debacle. But I am less persuaded that limited liability explains BP’s decisions at the corporate level. The company’s market value has declined by over $75 billion since April. Here was an entity with more than just skin in the game and looking more than just flayed at the moment. And yet, the company opted not to invest $500,000 in a secondary acoustic shut-off switch, which is essentially required in Norway and Brazil, and which Royal Dutch Shell and France’s Total SA sometimes use even when not required. BP’s backup plans B, C, and D all seemed to come out of the playbook for dealing with the 1979 Ixtoc disaster— none of them worked that well there, either. So why did the company take such risks?
I think part of the answer, for both toxic assets and toxic oil, has to do with a kind of groupthink that can take over among the smart folks who are supposed to be evaluating these risks. It’s so hard to be the one raising the possibility that real estate prices could decline nationally by 25% when it’s never happened before and all the guys who say it won’t are making money hand over fist. And this interacts with the forces mentioned above. When the probability of spectacular failure appears remote, and moreover it hasn’t happened yet, it’s hard to set up incentives, whether you’re talking about a corporation or a regulatory body, in which the person who makes sure that the risks stay contained is the person who gets rewarded. When everyone around you starts thinking that nothing can go wrong, it’s hard for you not to do the same. It can become awfully lonely in those environments to try to be the voice of prudence.
And yet, prudent judgment is the thing I most desperately wish decision-makers had more of in these times of dazzling new technological capabilities.
That was the point I was trying to make, but Hamilton makes it much more eloquently. Here is Ryan Avent:
After having a look at the Fed’s new Beige Book and at Ben Bernanke’s testimony to Congress, it’s impressive the extent to which the Fed acknowledges the economic headwinds facing the economy, only to basically repeat the forecast it’s been touting (with small nudges one way or another) for the past nine months””American economic growth of between 3% and 4% this year and next, settling down thereafter. I’m not sure if that’s reassuring or troubling.
The whole post is worth reading, but I’d like to comment on why I think the Fed’s view is troubling. Given the current inflation rate of 1%, the Fed is essentially forecasting 4.5% NGDP growth as far as the eye can see. That’s trend growth, if we assume that trend real GDP growth has fallen to 2.5% (a widely held view.) OK, so what does trend NGDP growth mean? It means the Fed is contributing nothing to the economic recovery. AD expansion is at rates you’d expect if we were at full employment. The entire recovery must be “financed” by below trend inflation. Alternatively, by shifts in the SRAS curve due to wage and price cuts. And recall that NGDP recently fell nearly 8% below trend. Even if half that was a permanent real shock, surely with 9.7% unemployment there must be some slack? Couldn’t the Fed just help us out a little bit? A tiny bit? Is there really nothing they can do?
Here is Tim Duy:
To summarize, the Fed believes we are facing another threat to demand, either via financial or real trade linkages, at a time when lending activity continues to fall, suggesting that monetary policy is too tight to begin with. But the Fed stance is to believe that monetary policy is on the verge of being too loose, and, if anything, planning needs to be made to tighten policy. At the same time, Fed policymakers also believe fiscal policy needs to turn toward tightening as well. Meanwhile, unemployment hovers just below 10%, nor is it expected to decline rapidly, and inflation continues to trend downward.
All of which together suggests that the Fed’s policy stance is seriously out of whack with policymaker’s interpretation of actual and potential economic developments. And I have trouble explaining the disconnect.
As I read Duy’s entire post, I tried to imagine what a Fed official might say in their defense. Usually I can do that, even when reading something with which I disagree. For instance, people often send me Krugman articles they object to. Even when I agree with Krugman, I can usually imagine how he could defend his argument against a critique. Tim Duy’s post seemed so persuasive that I can even imagine a credible counterargument.
Arnold Kling has some of his usual excellent posts on the housing crisis (here and here.) I learned that my anti-Fannie and Freddie views are considered racist among some members of the liberal elite. Ah yes, the racism accusation. The McCarthyism of the left. My reaction? Only a left-wing pinko commie would make that kind of accusation.
BTW, the McCarthy era was already ancient history by the time I was a teenager in 1970. I have to think we are rapidly approaching the time when people who recklessly throw out the charge of “racism” will look just as silly as those who accuse Obama of being a communist.