Archive for February 2020

 
 

Inflation has averaged 2.14% over the past 4 years

Yes, I know that that is CPI inflation, and the PCE inflation rate (1.74%) has undershot the Fed’s 2.0% over the past 4 years. That’s not my point.

Rather, I’d like to revisit some criticism I got in the comment section over the past 4 years, when I began to argue that TIPS spreads seemed slightly biased by a liquidity premium. Because conventional Treasuries are slightly more liquid than TIPS, it seems that investors are willing to accept a slightly lower rate of return on Treasuries. Thus the TIPS spread slightly underestimates the market’s expected rate of CPI inflation.

Over the past few years, 5-year TIPS spreads have averaged about 1.7%. Because TIPS use the CPI to adjust for inflation, it is appropriate to look at the CPI when judging the accuracy of TIPS forecasts.  (If you are not paying attention, this is my “I told you so” paragraph.)

On the other hand, the Fed targets PCE inflation, which tends to run below CPI inflation. Because the TIPS tend to underestimate CPI inflation, but CPI inflation runs higher than PCE inflation, these two biases partially offset.

In my view, the TIPS spread is actually a pretty good predictor of future PCE inflation, although if anything I think it probably slightly underestimates future PCE inflation. In other words, the TIPS spread may underestimate CPI inflation by a bit more than the CPI overestimates PCE inflation.

If I had to guess, I’d say PCE inflation is likely to average about 1.7% over the next 5 years, even though the TIPS spread suggests only 1.6% for CPI inflation. The consensus of private sector forecasters is for 2.0% PCE inflation during 2020-24, but they’ve pretty consistently overestimated inflation for a decade.  If you assume that the TIPS spread implies roughly 1.3% PCE inflation, then my prediction is roughly half way between the market and the survey forecast.

My hopeless dream that will never come true

As the Democratic Party self destructs before our very eyes (as I predicted in this blog last year), I desperately grasp for straws, despite knowing in my heart that Trump will be President for 5 more years. Here’s my latest pathetic fantasy:

Bill Clinton and Barack Obama go on national TV in a well publicized 1/2 hour TV special. They patiently explain why a self-professed socialist who honeymooned in the Soviet Union is not likely to be elected president in the world’s most capitalist country in the midst of an economic boom. That shouldn’t be too hard to do.  Especially because when Sanders was younger he said many many things that will allow the GOP to say he’s a communist, not just a socialist.  Do you think the GOP will fail to resurrect those quotes in campaign ads?

In the forlorn hope that Dem voters are not totally brain dead, and still have a lingering affection for those two (successful and semi-successful) former presidents, maybe they listen.

Then the big surprise. They both announce they plan to endorse Al Gore, who will enter the race the next day. They call on all moderate candidates to drop out of the race for the good of the country.

Al Gore has lots of advantages over Sanders. First, he’s younger than Sanders, despite having run for president in 1988. Second he’s already won the majority of votes in a presidential election, against a far tougher candidate than Trump. Most importantly, he appeals to both centrists and the left. He was a centrist while in office, but moved left after leaving office—opposing the Iraq War and becoming a fanatical advocate of fighting climate change.

Sanders is such an awful candidate that I’d support almost any GOP nominee over Sanders, even someone as awful as Jeff Sessions or (gasp) Lindsey Graham. Indeed there’s only one Republican that would make me support Sanders.

PS.  Off topic, I saw this headline in the National Review:

Bloomberg’s China Apologetics Should Disqualify Him from the Presidency

I also hate Bloomberg, and don’t want him anywhere near the White House.  But does the conservative, pro-Republican National Review really want to say that a candidate is disqualified to be president if he praises a foreign dictator?

Just asking.

I expect 2020 will be like one of those Central American elections where voters get to choose between an authoritarian thug who praises military people that torture and murder, and a socialist who likes Cuba.

We’ve truly become a banana republic.

Brainard on monetary policy reform

Lael Brainard gave a very good speech at the UC Booth School of Business in NYC, which begins by considering what went wrong during the recovery phase of the Great Recession:

Looking back at the international experience, the evidence suggests that forward guidance and balance sheet policies were broadly effective in providing accommodation following the financial crisis. But they were less effective when there were long delays in implementation or apparent inconsistencies among policy tools. It is important to distill key lessons from the past use of these tools in order to make them more effective in the future.

First, in some cases around the world, unconventional tools were implemented only after long delays and debate, which sapped confidence, tightened financial conditions, and weakened recovery. The delays often reflected concerns about the putative costs and risks of these policies, such as stoking high inflation and impairing market functioning. These costs and risks did not materialize or proved manageable, and I expect these tools to be deployed more forcefully and readily in the future.

Second, forward guidance proved to be vital during the crisis, but it took some time to recognize the importance of conditioning forward guidance on specific outcomes or dates and to align the full set of policy tools. In several cases, the targeted outcomes set too low a bar, which in turn diminished market expectations regarding monetary accommodation. In some cases, expectations regarding the timing of liftoff and asset purchase tapering worked at cross-purposes.

In addition, in some cases, it proved difficult to calibrate asset purchase programs smoothly over the course of the recovery. To the extent that the public is uncertain about the conditions that might trigger asset purchases, the scale of purchases, and how long the purchases might be sustained, it could undercut the efficacy of the policy. Furthermore, the cessation of asset purchases and subsequent balance sheet normalization can present challenges in communications and implementation.

Finally, in the fog of war, it was difficult for policymakers to distinguish clearly between temporary headwinds associated with the crisis and emerging structural features of the new normal. In part as a result, it took some time to integrate forward guidance and other unconventional policies seamlessly, and it took even longer to recognize that policy settings were unlikely to return to pre-crisis norms.

This misses the mistakes of 2008, when the Fed wasn’t at the zero bound, particularly the Fed’s excessive focus on inflation (rather than NGDP growth) and its putting too much weight on model forecasts of inflation relative to market forecasts.  But otherwise it’s a pretty good summary of mistakes made after 2008.

Brainard recommends a much more timely and expansive use of tools in the next recession, including interest rate caps and forward guidance.  She also favors “flexible average inflation targeting”.  That might sound worse than strict average inflation targeting, but if it’s an implicit nod to the fact that it’s NGDP that really matters, then maybe it would actually be better.  In other words, try to get back to the price level trend line when the deviation is caused by demand shocks, but not when caused by supply shocks.

NGDP level targeting would be even better, but that’s off the table right now, so Brainard is right to focus on those improvements that are the most feasible.

Toward the end she suggests that monetary policy might not be enough, and calls on Congress and regulators to do more, using countercyclical fiscal policy and countercyclical macroprudential financial regulations.  I think that’s being overly optimistic.

It’s unrealistic to expect Congress to engage is countercyclical fiscal policy; indeed fiscal policy has been highly procyclical in recent years.  Basically, the US is now a banana republic, and the Fed needs to understand that fact and behave accordingly. Banking regulation has also been procyclical, becoming more lax as the economy booms.  It’s really hard to overcome political pressures that keep pushing policy in a procyclical direction

Instead of relying of fiscal policy, I’d like to see the Fed ask Congress to give it additional tools.  Congress should let the Fed declare an emergency when rates fall to the zero bound, and allow the Fed to buy a much wider range of assets during the emergency.  If they wish, Congress could add a provision that the Fed must reduce its balance sheet when the emergency is over, and (without a waver from Congress) not allow the Fed to raise rates until “unconventional assets” (like stocks and corporate bonds) were first sold off.

If fiscal policy is to play any role, it should be for Congress to commit to a bailout of the Fed if its QE program leads to such large losses that the Fed’s assets fall to zero.  This is something that almost certainly will not happen in the foreseeable future.  But this commitment would add credibility to the sort of large-scale QE programs that might be needed in a deep recession.

In the past when I discuss this provision, commenters sometimes want to talk about a fiscal bailout of the Fed as something that might actually happen.  That’s not a productive discussion.  It’s not going to be needed in the foreseeable future.  (The currency stock alone is $1.8 trillion.)  The point is to remove any anxiety that Fed officials might have regarding a “whatever it takes” approach to stimulus.

Indeed I don’t think it’s even useful to talk about the Fed buying stocks, as that also seems unlikely to be necessary.  What is necessary is to convince that markets that the Fed would buy stocks if needed to hit their average inflation target.

A few comments on Parasite

Readers of this blog may recall that I named Parasite as one of my favorite films of 2019.  It’s recently been in the news due to its winning a Best Picture Oscar.

I’ve seen some reviews that didn’t seem to understand the film.  Some argued that it was unrealistic, not seeming to understand that it’s supposed to be unrealistic; it’s a black comedy.  Some pointed out that it commented on inequality in South Korea, without mentioning what sort of “comments” it made.  Whereas a Hollywood film on inequality would portray the poor as wholesome and hardworking and the rich as corrupt and lazy, this film did almost the opposite.

I read that this is the first foreign language film to win a Best Picture Oscar.  There’s also an Oscar for “Best Foreign Language Film.”  That raises the question of why this film won best picture.  While it’s a fine film, I’ve seen several dozen other Korean films of comparable quality.  Indeed it’s not even the best film by this director (I’d vote for “Memories of Murder”.)

Perhaps Hollywood is beginning to feel guilty about its past nationalism (especially now that we are in the Age of Trump.)  It’s not just that no foreign language film had won in the past, even worse, a number of them were nominated and lost.  If none had been nominated, then you could treat the two awards as separate categories, best English language film and best foreign language film.  By nominating some foreign language films for Best Picture, but never giving them top honors, Hollywood was saying, “we’ve looked around the world and never seen a foreign language film as good as what America produces.”  Ouch!  In 2020, that’s too jingoistic for even Hollywood.

I’d actually prefer they not allow foreign language films in the best picture category, as they’ll never be judged on a level playing field.  Alternatively, have three Oscars; best high-brow film, determined by highbrow critics. best middlebrow film, determined much like the current Best Picture, and best popular film, determined by box office receipts.  The same film would be allowed to compete in all three categories.

The Godfather would have won all three, but I’m not sure any other film would have (Birth of a Nation?,  Lord of the Rings III?)

Rear Window would have won highbrow and popular, but it wasn’t even nominated for Best Picture.  LOL.  Middlebrow people are the worst.

Here we go again

There’s a renewed danger of recession this year, and to explain why it’s worth revisiting the recent past. I have argued that we normally would have had a recession last year, but a nimble Fed was able to adjust policy in time to prevent the recession and create America’s first expansion of more than a decade.

On many occasions, Fed policymakers make contractionary errors late in a business cycle. The yield curve inversion such as occurred in March 2019 is normally a pretty good recession forecaster, but not perfect. It depends on how the Fed reacts. But just being far enough along in the business cycle that unemployment has fallen to the natural rate is likely as good a recession forecaster as the yield curve inversion, indeed they often go together.

The Fed avoided recession in 2019 because it ignored its Keynesian Phillips curve models that suggested overheating, and reduced rates three times. The Fed was looking at market indicators, not the unemployment rate. (Hmmm, who’s been suggesting the Fed be guided by market indicators?)

In early 2019, the trade war with China disrupted manufacturing and reduced the equilibrium (or “natural) interest rate. Fortunately, the Fed saw what was happening and responded. Now, in early 2020 the coronavirus is disrupting Chinese manufacturing and reducing the equilibrium interest rates. The yield curve has once again inverted (3m/10y). Let’s hope that the Fed sees what’s happening and once again responds aggressively. If so, there will be no recession. (Or we might luck out and the coronavirus fades away quickly.)

The consensus of economic forecasters (at the Philly Fed) calls for roughly 4.0% NGDP growth from 2020 Q1 to 2021 Q1. That’s 2.1% RGDP growth and roughly 1.9% inflation (using the PCE, not the deflator) The Hypermind prediction markets says 2.95%, which is quite a discrepancy.

The Philly survey of private economists has been consistently too optimistic on inflation for a decade, just like the Fed itself. But the discrepancy is presumably also due to a lower RGDP forecast at Hypermind. When I first noticed the discrepancy a few months back, I indicated that I was about halfway in between the two in my forecast. I’ll stick with that. Say 3.4% (1.7%/1.7%).

On balance, I don’t think there’ll be a recession this year. But if the Fed ignores market warnings that the equilibrium interest rate is falling, then a recession becomes much more likely. Let’s hope they pay attention. They’ve done such a nice job under Powell that it’d be a shame to see all those gains washed away.

Or as a Hollywood tough guy would say, “Nice expansion you got there Jay, it’d be a shame if something happened to it. How about 50 basis points?”