Archive for May 2013

 
 

Martin Feldstein, then and now

Here’s Martin Feldstein in 2011:

Until the fourth quarter of last year, the US economic recovery that began in the summer of 2009 was decidedly anemic. Annual GDP growth in the first three quarters of 2010 averaged only about 2.6% – and most of that was just inventory building. Without the inventory investment, the growth rate of final sales averaged less than 1%.

But the fourth quarter was very different. Annual GDP rose by 3.2% and growth of final sales jumped to a remarkable 7.1% year-on-year rate. True, much of that was due to a sharp decline in imports; but even the growth rate of final sales to domestic purchasers rose at a healthy 3.4% pace.

The key driver of the increase in final sales was a strong rise in consumer spending. Real personal consumer spending grew at a robust 4.4% rate, as spending on consumer durables soared by 21%. That meant that the acceleration of growth in consumer spending accounted for nearly 100% of the increase in GDP, with the rise in durable spending accounting for almost half of that increase.

The rise in consumer spending was not, however, due to higher employment or faster income growth. Instead, it reflected a fall in the personal saving rate. Household saving had risen from less than 2% of after-tax incomes in 2007 to 6.3% in the spring of 2010. But then the saving rate fell by a full percentage point, reaching 5.3% in December 2010.

A likely reason for the fall in the saving rate and resulting rise in consumer spending was the sharp increase in the stock market, which rose by 15% between August and the end of the year. That, of course, is what the Fed had been hoping for.

At the annual Fed conference at Jackson Hole, Wyoming in August, Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke explained that he was considering a new round of quantitative easing (dubbed QE2), in which the Fed would buy a substantial volume of long-term Treasury bonds, thereby inducing bondholders to shift their wealth into equities. The resulting rise in equity prices would increase household wealth, providing a boost to consumer spending.

To be sure, there is no proof that QE2 led to the stock-market rise, or that the stock-market rise caused the increase in consumer spending. But the timing of the stock-market rise, and the lack of any other reason for a sharp rise in consumer spending, makes that chain of events look very plausible.

The magnitude of the relationship between the stock-market rise and the jump in consumer spending also fits the data. Since share ownership (including mutual funds) of American households totals approximately $17 trillion, a 15% rise in share prices increased household wealth by about $2.5 trillion. The past relationship between wealth and consumer spending implies that each $100 of additional wealth raises consumer spending by about four dollars, so $2.5 trillion of additional wealth would raise consumer spending by roughly $100 billion.

That figure matches closely the fall in household saving and the resulting increase in consumer spending. Since US households’ after-tax income totals $11.4 trillion, a one-percentage-point fall in the saving rate means a decline of saving and a corresponding rise in consumer spending of $114 billion – very close to the rise in consumer spending implied by the increased wealth that resulted from the gain in share prices.

And here’s Martin Feldstein in 2013:

The Federal Reserve recently announced that it will increase or decrease the size of its monthly bond-buying program in response to changing economic conditions. This amounts to a policy of fine-tuning its quantitative-easing program, a puzzling strategy since the evidence suggests that the program has done little to raise economic growth while saddling the Fed with an enormous balance sheet.

. . .

Here’s how it is supposed to work. When the Fed buys long-term government bonds and mortgage-backed securities, private investors are no longer able to buy those long-term assets. Investors who want long-term securities therefore have to buy equities. That drives up the price of equities, leading to more consumer spending.

But despite the Fed’s current purchases of $85 billion a month and an accumulation of more than $2 trillion of long-term assets, the economy is limping along with per capita gross domestic product rising at less than 1% a year. Although it is impossible to know what would happen without the central bank’s asset purchases, the data imply that very little increase in GDP can be attributed to the so-called portfolio-balance effect of the Fed’s actions.

Even if all of the rise in the value of household equities since quantitative easing began could be attributed to the Fed policy, the implied increase in consumer spending would be quite small. According to the Federal Reserve’s Flow of Funds data, the total value of household stocks and mutual funds rose by $3.6 trillion between the end of 2009 and the end of 2012. Since past experience implies that each dollar of increased wealth raises consumer spending by about four cents, the $3.6 trillion rise in the value of equities would raise the level of consumer spending by about $144 billion over three years, equivalent to an annual increase of $48 billion or 0.3% of nominal GDP.

This 0.3% overstates the potential contribution of quantitative easing to the annual growth of GDP, since some of the increase in the value of household equities resulted from new saving and the resulting portfolio investment rather than from the rise in share prices. More important, the rise in equity prices also reflected a general increase in earnings per share and an increase in investor confidence after 2009 that the economy would not slide back into recession.

.  .  .

In short, it isn’t at all clear that the Fed’s long-term asset purchases have raised equity values as the portfolio balance theory predicted. Even if it did account for the entire rise in equity values, the increase in household equity wealth would have only a relatively small effect on consumer spending and GDP growth.

There’s no direct contradiction, but the tone sure has changed.

BTW, QE works through the expected hot potato effect boosting NGDP, plus sticky wages, not via reduced consumer saving.

Update:  That was poorly worded.  I meant “in the presence of sticky wages.”  I did not mean to imply QE boosts wages in the short run.

PS.  NGDP bleg:  I saw that eurozone RGDP fell 0.2% in Q1, but can’t find NGDP data.  I hope they don’t report NGDP with a lag like the British do, it’s impossible to calculate RGDP w/o knowing NGDP

HT:  Vivian Darkbloom

It’s even worse than Yglesias believes

Here’s Matt Yglesias:

Ben Bernanke’s appearances before Congress are usually a parade of clueless questions, but Sen. Amy Klobuchar of Minnesota just asked him a great one. Noting that some members of Congress think the Fed should drop its dual mandate on inflation and unemployment and just focus on price stability, she asked Bernanke to explain what he would do differently if the mandate changed.

Bernanke hemmed and hawed a bit, but the crux of his answer was: nothing.

He seemed to interpret the question as perhaps an attack on his inflation record, but his answer was a damning attack on his growth record. (His answer starts around the 39-minute mark here.) Bernanke noted that “inflation, if anything, is a little bit too low” and said that even though many foreign central banks have a single mandate: “I think our inflation record is as good as really any major central bank, and so there’s not really been a sacrifice in that respect.”*

That’s a huge tell right there. Bernanke can’t name a single way in which his policy would change if Congress rescinded his legal mandate to attempt to maximize employment. In other words, he’s ignoring that mandate. The Federal Reserve’s attitude with respect to price inflation has been identical to what its attitude would be in a world in which it wasn’t legally required to care about inflation.

(I believe the final word in that quotation should have been ‘unemployment.’)

I’ve made similar observations over the years, but even more forcefully.  The Fed has undershot its inflation target over the past 5 years, and is expected to continue undershooting over the next few years.  In other words, if the Fed had followed the advice of those hawks who want them to focus on their inflation mandate like a laser, policy would be more expansionary.  The hawks should actually be complaining that policy is too tight.  If you applied a model of “revealed preference,” it would seem that the Fed enjoys making the unemployed suffer.  Obviously that’s not true, which indicates that the Fed is deeply confused about the policy it has actually implemented.

Kudos to Klobuchar.  Too bad her colleagues don’t know how to ask a follow-up question.

I’m currently trying to dig out from under a mountain of work–so blogging will continue to be sporadic.

Zero fiscal multiplier: Example # 213

From today’s news:

The marked improvement in the labor market since the U.S. central bank began its third round of quantitative easing, or QE3, has added an edge to calls by some policy hawks to dial down the stimulus. The roughly 50 percent jump in monthly job creation since the program began has even won renewed support from centrists, raising at least some chance the Fed could ratchet back its buying as early as next month.

I hope I don’t have to do any more of these.  The fiscal multiplier theory is as dead as John Cleese’s parrot.  The growth in jobs didn’t slow with fiscal austerity, it sped up!  And the Fed is saying that any job improvement due to fiscal stimulus will be offset with tighter money.  They talk like the multiplier is zero, and their actions produce a zero multiplier.  Has there ever been a more decisive refutation of a major economic theory?

Yes there has; the conservative view that QE and big deficits would lead to higher inflation and higher interest rates.

PS.  Saturos  asked me about this exchange on twitter.  The expected fiscal multiplier is roughly zero.  And for policy purposes it is the expected fiscal multiplier that matters, not the actual ex post multiplier (which is impossible to calculate in any case.)

Mexico and China

I wrote this a while ago and probably shouldn’t post it. “Not scientific.”  But I will anyway.  Don’t have time for anything new.

During the week of turmoil in Boston, I was on vacation in the Yucatan.  It was slightly surreal watching CNN and seeing the police stake out an area just a mile from where I live.

I’ve travelled to Mexico off and on since 1970, and like the country.  But there are some annoyances.  We were scammed several times while using credit cards (Pemex, Dollar Rental Car, etc)  I’d suggest using cash.  I should have been more careful, as the gas stations used to scam us back in the 1970s, although then it was by not setting the gauge back to zero before pumping gas.

This is one area where Mexico seems to lag China, where we’ve had far fewer problems with scams (although I don’t doubt there are plenty there as well.)  Here’s another difference I noticed recently.  In Mexico the teachers are upset that the government is going to try to improve the education system.  It seems teacher positions are bought and sold, and can even be handed down from one generation to the next.  That’s the sort of practice that is more common in low income countries like India than middle income countries like China.

If you go to the Yucatan, I’d stay in the Tulum area (or Merida), rather than Cancun.  Rent a car and you can explore the interior.  We went to Valladolid, which seemed virtually unchanged since I drove through in the 1970s, indeed it probably doesn’t look much different from the 1870s, or the 1670s. BTW, I recommend reading Stephen’s two books on the Yucatan (from 1840), if you plan to visit.  We didn’t have time for Merida and Campeche, but I saw them on an earlier trip and they are both worth visiting.

I was struck by the differences with China.  If you went to a small city in China today, it would look totally changed from the 1970s, indeed from 2003.  This trip made me more convinced than ever that China will blow right by Mexico in terms of GDP/person.

That’s not to say that China is “better” in any overall sense.  Mexicans seem very friendly and happy (and surveys confirm that it scores high in “life satisfaction.”) It’s full of charming old colonial cities and the climate is delightful.  China . . . well . . . not so much.  In utilitarian terms China may never catch Mexico.  And I’m a utilitarian.

But anyone who travels from Mexico to China can’t help but notice the vast differences in economic momentum.  Despite all its very real flaws, China has a system that generates ever higher GDP at an awesome rate, even in towns the size of Valladolid.  It’s not pretty, but it’s relentless and grimly effective.

The “disappointing” 7.7% RGDP number from Q1 (distorted by lack of adjustment for leap year) has led some to wonder if the China boom is over.  It isn’t.

PS.  I was originally going to entitle this post; “speed bumps on the road to prosperity.”  The argument was that Mexico has far more speed bumps than China, because it’s a more lawless society.  But then I realized that some commenter would probably point out there are speed bumps in Norway or Switzerland or some other rich country.  Hence my schlock theory got relegated to a footnote.

PPS.  The “lawless” nature of Mexico does have its charms.  In the 1970s we could go anywhere in Chichen Itza; I stood on top of one of the hoops in the ball court.  Now everything’s roped off—it’s getting more like the US.  But they still don’t close down entire cities of a million people because one 19 year old killer is on the run.  Thank God.

PPPS.  I saw that Matt Yglesias recently got into trouble by daring to tell the truth about Bangladesh:

It seems like the entire Internet has registered its objections to this piece I wrote on the Bangladesh factory disaster. And I have to say that my overwhelming personal response, as a writer and as a human being, is to be annoyed by the responses that I’m getting. But let me try to be mature about it instead and say””what happened in Bangladesh is a tragedy and a human disaster, and to the best of my knowledge it’s also quite literally a criminal disaster under the existing laws of Bangladesh.

It also seems like “the entire internet” lets feelings trump reason.  Don’t let them push you around Matt.  The Paul Krugman of the 1990s would have said the same thing.

Money isn’t “easy”– A rant

I am traveling today, so only have time to complain about some themes I keep coming across when reading the press and speaking to people out in the real world.  No links.

1.  There is no reason at all for the ECB to look around for transmission mechanisms to boost the eurozone economy.  Europe is in recession because the ECB WANTS IT TO BE IN RECESSION.  Yes, the ECB doesn’t know that it wants a recession, but the NGDP growth it is producing will inevitably produce a recession in the eurozone.  OK, they aren’t even targeting NGDP, but the highly flawed CPI including oil and VAT that they are trying to hold well below 2% will inevitably produce the sort of slow NGDP growth that will inevitably produce recession.

2.  The ECB is not at the zero bound.  Over the past few years they’ve been repeatedly steering eurozone inflation through conventional policies of raising and lowering the short term interest rate.  If they had a broken transmission mechanism they would not have been raising rates during 2011.

3.  And even if they were out of room to cut rates, they are not out of paper and ink.  There is no need to look for wacky UK-style proposals to stimulate bank lending–that’s what got us into this mess in the first place.  They need to do monetary stimulus, WHICH HAS NOTHING TO DO WITH BANK LENDING.  More currency depreciates the value of a euro note for the same reason that a big apple crop depreciates the value of an apple.  Does a big apple harvest only cause apple prices to fall if bank lending is stimulated?  Of course unlike apples, currency is durable.  Hence the increase needs to be (expected to be) at least partly permanent.

4.  Money is very tight in the eurozone, using the Bernanke NGDP/inflation criterion for tightness.  They don’t need new ideas, they need to adopt an easy money policy.  The bank lending channel was just as broken in 2010, when eurozone GDP was rising.

5.  Is there any excuse for the press to still be talking about “easy money” throughout the developed world?  (A view that seems to be based on little more than low interest rates.)  I mean seriously, after the last 6 months in Japan, how can people still equate easy money with low rates?  Just to refresh your memory, Japan’s had near zero rates for 16 years and nothing has changed in the past 6 months.  Yet when you talk to finance-types you get the impression the current stock market booms are due to low interest rates caused by easy money.  That “easy money” policy of low rates  brought the Japanese stock market from 39,000 in the early 1990s to 8675 by mid November 2012.

6.  Then Japan really did adopt a slightly easier money policy, and stocks soared 70% in 6 months, even though the dominant paleo-Keynesian narrative says that monetary stimulus has no effects at zero rates.  Oh wait, they’ve just invented a new theory!  How convenient!  At zero rates the liquidity trap applies to output but not stock prices, which are raised though the finance equivalent of “immaculate conception.”

7.  For anyone with two eyes, the past few months have decisively confirmed the Bernanke/Friedman/Mishkin/market monetarist view that low rates do not mean easy money.  That high rates don’t mean tight money.  And yet the other 99.999999% of humanity continues to blather on about “tight money” in 1979 and the Latin American hyperinflations, and “easy money” in the 1930s and the late 1990s Japanese deflation, and the current morass.

8.  Again, eurozone tight money is keeping eurozone NGDP flat, and that’s a sufficient condition for a recession.  Yes, they may also have supply-side problems, but that’s beside the point.  Tight money is a sufficient condition for recession.  They can adopt a policy of 4% NGDP growth if they want to; they simply don’t want to.  Until that dynamic changes, the eurozone will continue to under-perform.

9.  Nothing is gained by disaggregating the eurozone.  Yes, some countries are healthier than others, but easier money will boost the overall eurozone NGDP, and that’s likely to help the weak as much as the strong, perhaps more.  Recall that the current tight money policy HURT THE WEAK MUCH MORE THAN THE STRONG.